Main content

Intellectual property reflects an economic trade off. Too generous then good ideas will take too long to copy, adapt and spread; but too stingy and we might not see any good ideas

When the great novelist Charles Dickens arrived in America in 1842, he was hoping to put an end to pirated copies of his work in the US. They circulated there with impunity because the United States granted no copyright protection to non-citizens. Patents and copyright grant a monopoly, and monopolies are bad news. Dickens鈥檚 British publishers will have charged as much as they could get away with for copies of Bleak House; cash-strapped literature lovers simply had to go without. But these potential fat profits encourage new ideas. It took Dickens a long time to write Bleak House. If other British publishers could have ripped it off like the Americans, perhaps he wouldn鈥檛 have bothered. As Tim Harford explains, intellectual property reflects an economic trade-off 鈥 a balancing act. If it鈥檚 too generous to the creators then good ideas will take too long to copy, adapt and spread. But if it鈥檚 too stingy then maybe we won鈥檛 see the good ideas at all.

Producer: Ben Crighton
Editors: Richard Knight and Richard Vadon

(Image: Copyright stamp, Credit: Arcady/Shutterstock)

Available now

9 minutes

Last on

Mon 15 May 2017 03:50GMT

Sources and related links

Ronald V. Bettig - Copyrighting Culture: The Political Economy of Intellectual Property (Oxford: Westview Press) 1996 p13听

Christopher May - 鈥淭he Venetian Moment: New Technologies, Legal Innovation and the Institutional Origins of Intellectual Property鈥 Prometheus 20:2 159-179 (2002听

Dickens made 拢38,000. In inflation-adjusted terms that鈥檚 more than 拢3,000,000 in today鈥檚 money, and relative to the cost of labour it is nearly 拢25,000,000

Broadcasts

  • Sat 13 May 2017 02:50GMT
  • Sat 13 May 2017 19:50GMT
  • Mon 15 May 2017 03:50GMT

Podcast